Skip to content

We Need A New Model


On  reading the reports of DPM Tharman’s speech at the World Bank-Singapore Infrastructure Finance Summit yesterday, I was surprised how sanguine he was about the likely global recession and its effects on Singapore. While it is true to say that “we’ve got the fiscal space to deal with it”, he seems to view it as a temporary hiatus after which growth will resume according to the familiar Singapore economic model. That is, growth fuelled by exports and an external surplus that is over 20% of GDP.

Would that was true but sadly this is not likely to be a temporary phenomenon. The real burden of private sector debt, exacerbated by a mistaken policy of cutting public sector debt through fiscal austerity rather than through growth, in Europe and the US, means that consumers will continue to cut back and these economies’ appetite for imports will decline. At the same time, quantitative easing by the Fed and warnings by the US government against currency manipulation have pushed down the value of the US dollar when in the past it might have been propped up by buying from Asian central banks determined to maintain a competitive advantage. So, while we may be able to deal with it short-term by increased infrastructure spending or a renewal of wage subsidies, it would be a mistake to assume that there do not have to be permanent changes in the structure of our economy and a move towards higher levels of domestic consumption and lower levels of saving and net exports if we are to maintain economic growth longer term. The penny does not seem to have dropped here yet.

Secondly, and following on from the first point, he went on to say that he felt Asian policymakers have to focus on increasing investment rates in the region in order to create higher long-term growth. In isolation there is nothing to argue with here. It is a given in most economic growth models that raising investment rates raises the level of economic growth.

However higher levels of investment on their own are likely to be subject to diminishing returns. This was the experience of most of the so-called Asian “tiger” economies over the last twenty years and was drawn attention to in several academic studies, most notably by Paul Krugman. Of at least equal importance would be raising the productivity of existing investment, something that Singapore has notably failed to do. If the increased investment goes into raising the productive capacity of the economy without raising domestic demand then the investment is unlikely to be able to earn an economic return. The days of reliance on export-led growth are likely over, at least for now, for the reasons cited in the paragraph above.  While Tharman is right to point out that governments should be prepared to raise infrastructure investment, by borrowing if necessary given current low interest rates, the private sector is unlikely to follow suit and invest if there is no underlying demand. Without measures to raise domestic demand, government investment in infrastructure may end up being wasted or underutilised. This was the experience of Japan during its long deflation beginning in the 1990s.  Endless public works programmes and investments in infrastructure did not succeed in appreciably boosting the growth rate. This was because the increased spending was clawed back by raising taxes which largely negated the effects of the extra spending in the first place.

The moral of the story here is that, just as Singapore cannot rely any more on a growth model based on running a structural surplus through low consumption and high net exports and savings, so developing countries cannot assume that reliance on an export and investment-led model, as Tharman seems to be suggesting, will provide a route to higher economic growth. The world has changed and we need to move away from these outdated growth models.

Tharman also spoke about capital inflows which are a particular concern to the MAS as they may not only lead to a domestic asset bubble but also result in losses for the central bank on the holdings of foreign currency it is obliged to buy if the Singapore Dollar subsequently appreciates. So far the MAS has allowed the Singapore dollar to appreciate some 19% against the Euro and 11% against the US Dollar over the past year. However the consequences for the domestic economy are starting to be felt as Singaporean exports lose competitiveness and tourists find Singapore too expensive.

This problem has been brought into sharper focus by the announcement today that the Swiss National Bank is prepared to buy unlimited amounts of foreign currency to prevent the Swiss Franc from rising above 1.20 to the US Dollar. The announcement may precipitate more speculative inflows into the Singapore Dollar if that is still seen as a one-way bet by speculators with even greater adverse consequences for output and employment if the currency rises further. While our economy does need to shift away from an over dependence on exports, the severity and speed of the adjustment should be moderated. In light of the SNB announcement, MAS should seriously consider stepping up its purchases of foreign currency in order to prevent too rapid an appreciation.  However this may prove futile unless we go down the same route as the SNB and draw a line in the sand above which our currency will not be allowed to rise.

7 Comments »

  1. PS I am assuming the supply of Sing Dlrs remains unchanged in both cases. If the MAS were to print Sing Dlrs to drive its value down, as the Swiss intend to do with the CHF, wouldn’t that fuel domestic inflation? Still the same dilemma?

    Like

    • In order to peg the currency the MAS would have to undertake to supply an unlimited amount of S$ at the fixed exchange rate. It could choose to “sterilize” the intervention and prevent the money supply from increasing. by borrowing the S$ from domestic holders but this would likely involve the MAS in large losses as it would probably have to pay a higher rate of interest on the S$ it borrowed than it receives on the foreign currency it purchases (0%). This is the dilemma confronting Japan and China. If they get the S$ by printing money or borrowing from the banking system then the money supply may rise if the banks choose to use the increased supply of reserve assets to make more loans. However it is simplistic to say that this would necessarily lead to higher inflation given global spare capacity and lack of demand from borrowers in the first place.

      Like

  2. Hi Kenneth,

    I am not an economist. Would you be good enough to clarify these remarks in your last para?

    “The announcement may precipitate more speculative inflows into the Singapore Dollar if that is still seen as a one-way bet …”

    The assumption here is that with one avenue for currency speculation blocked (the Swiss Franc), “hot” money could flow into the Sing Dollar thereby causing it to appreciate. Yet, later in the para you say:

    “MAS should seriously consider stepping up its purchases of foreign currency in order to prevent too rapid an appreciation”.

    Aren’t these two statements contradictory ie doesn’t “speculative inflow” equal “stepping up purchases of foreign currency” with both resulting in appreciation of the Sing Dollar or am I missing something?

    Like

  3. paul tan, I’m sorry to say the comment in your para three reflects what is wrong with government thinking in this area – yet another blind spot.

    Centres of research excellence such as Oxford and Cambridge and Cambridge, Massachusetts developed after hundreds of years of efforts. Singapore’s mercantile government with its short term horizons has not even begun to understand this. A single project, the Human Genome Project was started in 1990 with funding of US$ 3 b and complete mapping has still not been achieved, let alone development of commercial applications such as disease control. Unless we have a time horizon of, say, 30 to 50 years, much of the money that is being poured into developing the R&D sector in general is likely to be wasted. I have spoken to engineers working on R&D in Singapore and they tell me of their frustration at working constantly under pressure to deliver commercial results. True academic work takes years, sometimes a lifetime, to bear fruit. Ask the scientists at CERN.

    Such knowledge based work is an obvious area that the Singapore government can develop. The irony is that it has the money to do so but not a clue on how to go about it.

    Like

  4. We need to develop smarter Singaporeans — as in more creative and productive despite shorter working hours. Education system is not doing this at the moment.

    Like

  5. I disagree with your view point that Singapore has to rebalance from an export-oriented model to domestic consumption, the reason being that small economies can afford to run up persistent trade surplus. Switzerland is one such example of a small economy running up a persistent trade surplus with its Euro-bloc trading partners, hence the need to peg the Swiss Franc to the Euro to cap Franc strength.

    Yes, I do agree with you that the current Singapore model of simply increasing factors of production to grow the economy without commensurate increase in total factor productivity is an intellectually bankrupt model.

    PS. Note that Singapore has spent like some USD 5B to USD 10B over the last ten years in bio-tech research without anything to show for it, Yes, there were foreign bigwigs in the biomedical field that were lure here to research, tons of research were published. But in the critical area where it matters, such as new drugs or new cure, it was a total bust.

    Like

Leave a Reply